icon

What do you think you're worth?

Steven J. Brams Share this page

What do you think you're worth?

Steven J. Brams
March 2008

Bonuses are a fact of business life. Last year the Guardian newspaper calculated that the cash rewards paid to London's financial chiefs comfortably outstripped the UK's entire transport budget. With such large sums at stake, envy is bound to raise its ugly head, never a good thing for company morale. So how should you decide who gets how much? Steven J. Brams suggests a method that's not only fair, but also encourages honesty.

A cake

What's a fair share?

One of the most difficult problems managers face is how to allocate bonuses to members of a team when there is scant information on the contribution of each member to the team's success. We'll look at a procedure whereby the members of a team assess the contributions of everybody, including themselves. It rewards honest self-assessments by motivating members to say what other members think they deserve. Members receive more or less what they request, avoiding disappointment and obviating recriminations.

Imagine that you're a member of a five-person team that has worked hard over the past year on an important project for your company. Management is pleased with the team's effort but is not well-informed about how much each team member contributed to the project's success. Management could, of course, ask the team leader — call him or her L — to assess the contributions of the team members. But there are two problems with this approach:

  • L may be biased for or against certain members in a way that doesn't reflect the views of most other members;
  • Management must also assess the contributions of L, which will be difficult if the other team members are not asked to evaluate L.

As an alternative, I propose not only that L assess the other team members and that they assess L but, in addition, that each member (including L) provide a self-assessment. This raises the question of whether the team members would be honest in their assessments and self-assessments. Might they not be inclined to inflate their self-assessments at the expense of their assessments of others?

The procedure

Assume the following rules are used to allocate the total bonus of a team to each of its members:

  1. Members rate themselves and each other on, say, a 5-point scale,
    1 2 3 4 5
    where the greater the number, the higher the rating. For one's ratings to count, however, they must sum to five times the median rating, which is 3; in other words they must sum to 15.
  2. The total bonus is allocated according to the difference between a member's average rating by others and his or her self-rating.
  3. The first disbursement of the total bonus goes to the team member with the greatest difference, giving this member a bonus commensurate with his or her self-rating.
  4. Step 3 is repeated, with disbursements going to members with smaller and smaller differences (possibly negative) until the total bonus is exhausted.

A simple example illustrates how this scheme works. The ratings of each team member are given across each row in the table below. Team members have been labelled 1, 2, 3, 4 and 5, with L being given the number 1. The ratings include a self-rating (S) and an average rating (A) by the other team members. The difference, A − S, is shown in the last column. It is positive if a member underestimates — in the eyes of the other members — his or her value to the team and negative if this member overestimates his or her value.

The columns show how each member
assessed everyone, including him or herself
1 (L) 2 3 4 5 A A-S
Member 1 3 (S) 2 2 3 5 3.00 0.00
Member 2 3 4(S) 2 3 1 2.25 −1.75
Member 3 4 4 2 (S) 5 1 3.50 +1.50
Member 4 4 1 5 2 (S) 3 3.25 +1.25
Member 5 1 4 4 2 5 (S) 2.75 −2.25
Sum 15 15 15 15 15 - -

To illustrate how the differences are calculated, consider the self-rating of member 1, the leader L, which is 3. Because L's average rating by others, which is (2 + 2 + 3 + 5)/4, is also 3, L's difference is 3 − 3 = 0. This means that L's self-assessment is right on target with other team members' assessments. By comparison, members 3 and 4 underestimate their value (their average ratings by others are greater than their self-ratings), whereas members 2 and 5 overestimate their value (their average ratings by others are less than their self-ratings).

Ratings into Bonuses

Money

Did you want more?

How do we translate these differences into specific bonuses for each team member? Suppose that management decides that the total bonus for the team will be £500,000, with L to receive £140,000 if his or her difference is 0, which is the case. (If this were not the case, a procedure similar to the one I discuss next for the other team members would be followed.) Thus, L will receive £140,000, with the remainder, £360,000, to be divided among the four other team members according to their differences.

Now if £360,000 is divided equally among all the team members, each would get £90,000. But management wants to add to this amount for good performance and subtract from this amount for bad performance. Suppose it decides to associate the following amounts with each rating:

A rating of 1 gives £70,000
A rating of 2 gives £80,000
A rating of 3 gives £90,000
A rating of 4 gives £100,000
A rating of 5 gives £110,000

Now we apply the rules to determine the bonuses. According to rule 3, we start with the greatest positive difference and so give member 3 what he or she requested, which translates from 2 into £80,000. Next, member 4's self-rating of 2 also translates into £80,000, and then member 2's self-rating of 4 translates into £100,000.

So far all members, starting with the member 3, have been able to receive exactly their requests. This leaves £100,000 remaining for member 5, or £10,000 less than the £110,000 to which member 5's self-rating of 5 would entitle him or her.

To summarize, members' bonuses, along with their average ratings by others, their self-ratings, and the differences, are shown in the table below:

Team member Average rating by others (A) Self-Rating (S) Difference (A - S) Bonus
1 (L) 3.00 3 0 £140,000
2 2.25 4 −1.75 £100,000
3 3.50 2 +1.50 £80,000
4 3.25 2 +1.25 £80,000
5 2.75 5 −2.25 £100,000

It may seem bizarre that members 3 and 4, with higher average ratings than members 2 and 5, each get £20,000 less because they underestimated their worth. But these results show precisely why such an outcome would almost never occur!

Honesty pays

If bonuses are allocated as I have illustrated, team members will have an overriding incentive to rate themselves honestly, neither underestimating nor overestimating their worth in the eyes of others. If they underestimate, as did members 3 and 4, they get their low requests. If they overestimate, they get what remains in the pool, which could be very little if their overestimates put them last in line to get a bonus (their bonus could even be zero if the pool is exhausted by this time).

Two business men

Honesty's better than intrigue.

To illustrate, suppose that members 3 and 4 give themselves ratings of 3, downgrading somebody else to keep their sums equal to 15. Then they would both receive bonuses of £90,000, with member 3 still below his or her average rating by others.

After the subtraction of £180,000 from £360,000, members 2 and 5 would draw from a pool of £180,000, rather than £200,000, that they drew from in the original example. Assuming member 2 is paid off next because his or her difference is greater than member 5's, then member 2 will, as before, receive £100,000. But this leaves only £80,000 for member 5, whose self-rating is the most out of line with the ratings of others, even though member 5 does not receive the lowest average rating of others (member 2 does).

Clearly, team members have an incentive to rate themselves as others see them, receiving bonuses commensurate with their self-ratings. In particular, they have no incentive to overestimate their contributions, because they will be the last to be paid out of a pool that that could have been substantially diminished or even exhausted.

Conclusions

I conclude that team members will have a strong incentive to make accurate self-assessments of their contributions to a project. In doing so, they will be motivated to seek the opinions of others, because the average of others' ratings, in comparison to their self-ratings, affects how big their bonuses will be. (The median rating of others could be substituted for the average rating to make the procedure invulnerable to a member who, for strategic reasons, gives a very high or very low rating to another member.) The influence of other members' ratings induces members to be responsible in their self-ratings, attenuating wishful thinking and self-delusion.

Perhaps the greatest advantage of making it rational for team members to align their expectations to those of others is that these expectations will be met. Members will get what they and others think they deserve — neither more nor less — thereby avoiding disappointment and obviating recriminations.

Addendum: eliminating self-ratings

The preceding procedure can be simplified by eliminating self-ratings and allowing members of a team to rate only other members of the team. To illustrate, assume members A, B, and C rate each of the other two members on a 3-point scale (1 = below average, 2 = average; 3 = above average) and must give an average rating of 2 to the other two members. Here is an example:

The columns show how
each member assessed everyone,
including him or herself
A B C Sum
Member A - 3 2 5
Member B 1 - 2 3
Member C 3 1 - 4
Average 2 2 2 -

Thus, A receives the highest average rating of 5/2 = 2.5, C the next-highest of 4/2 = 2, and B the lowest of 3/2 = 1.5 (see the sums in the last column of the above table). This system is honesty-inducing in the sense that no member can help himself or herself by being insincere since his or her ratings of other members have no effect on his or her own rating.

Of course, two (or more) members could agree to collude in rating each other highly, but there is no way this agreement can be enforced if ratings are secret and there are more than a few other members (not just the three in the example). In such a situation, the outcome would not be able to pinpoint any member as the one who broke an agreement. By contrast, with only three members, giving somebody a worse rating than agreed to could, when the results are announced, reveal a double-cross.


About the author

Steven J. Brams is Professor of Politics at New York University. He is the author or co-author of 14 books that involve applications of game theory and social choice theory to voting and elections, bargaining and fairness, international relations, and the Bible and theology. His most recent books are Mathematics and Democracy: Designing better Voting and Fair-Division Procedures, The Win-Win Solution (with Alan D Taylor) and Fair Division: From Cake-Cutting to Dispute Resolution. He is a Fellow of the American Association for the Advancement of Science, the Public Choice Society, a Guggenheim Fellow, and was a Russell Sage Foundation Visiting Scholar and a President of the the Peace Science Society (International) and the Public Choice Society.

Read more about...